Добавил:
Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:

учебный год 2023 / (Encyclopedia of Law and Economics 5) Boudewijn Bouckaert-Property Law and Economics -Edward Elgar Publishing (2010)

.pdf
Скачиваний:
3
Добавлен:
21.02.2023
Размер:
1.62 Mб
Скачать

The economics of slavery 215

Labor-force transitions and profits from slavery

One potent piece of evidence supporting the notion that slavery provides pecuniary benefits is this: slavery often gives way to other forms of organizing the labor force when the costs and risks of maintaining slaves become too large. In Europe, for example, serfdom evolved in part as a way of shifting some of the risks of poor crop yields away from masters (Bloch, 1975; Bush, 1996). A similar system arose within Africa in the nineteenth century. Slaves paid their masters for the right to work on their own; in exchange, masters no longer paid for the slaves’ upkeep (Watson, 1980). The Spanish Crown for a time favored a system of forced labor called encomienda, whereby the indigenous population could not be bought, sold, rented, bequeathed, or removed from the area. Scholars have speculated that this form of coercion, relative to outright slavery, reduced threats to the security of the Crown’s interest (Yeager, 1995). Thus, other types of labor take the place of slaves when slavery costs too much.

In like fashion, slavery replaces other labor when it becomes relatively cheaper. In the early US colonies, for example, indentured servitude was common. As the demand for skilled servants (and therefore their wages) rose in England, the cost of indentured servants went up in the colonies. At the same time, second-generation slaves became more productive than their forebears because they spoke English and did not have to adjust to life in a strange new world. Consequently, the balance of labor shifted away from indentured servitude and toward slavery (Galenson, 1982, 1984, and 1986; Grubb, 1985 and 1994; Engerman, 1992). Georgia offers a compelling example. Its original 1732 charter prohibited ownership of black slaves. Yet by 1750 the trustees of the new colony had to relax the prohibition because Georgia growers simply could not compete with producers elsewhere who utilized lower-cost slave labor (Grindle, 1990).

Profitability and race

One element that contributed to the profitability of New World slavery was, for several reasons, the African heritage of the slaves. Africans, more than native people, were accustomed to the discipline of agricultural practices and knew metalworking. Some scholars surmise that Africans, relative to Europeans, could better withstand tropical diseases and, unlike native Americans, also had some exposure to the European disease pool (Coelho and McGuire, 1997).

Perhaps the most distinctive feature of Africans, however, was their skin color. Because they looked different from their masters, their movements were easy to monitor. Denying slaves education, property ownership, contractual rights, and other things enjoyed by those in power was simple: one need only look at people to ascertain their likely status. Using color

216 Property law and economics

was a low-cost way of distinguishing slaves from free persons. For this reason, perhaps, early colonial practices that freed slaves who converted to Christianity quickly faded away. Deciphering true religious beliefs is far more difficult than establishing skin color. Other slave societies have used distinguishing marks like brands or long hair to denote slaves, yet color is far more immutable and therefore better as a cheap way of keeping slaves separate.

Among those who profited from slavery were men who worked as slave catchers and received fees for returning escaped slaves to their masters. Because skin color was the principal identifying mark, however, free blacks also faced the horrifying possibility of capture and sale.

Efficiency of antebellum slavery

So New World slavery was profitable; was it an efficient way of organizing the workforce? On this question, considerable controversy remains. Slavery might well profit masters, but only because they exploit their chattel. What is more, slavery could have locked people into a method of production and way of life that might later have proven burdensome.

Fogel and Engerman (1974) claim that slaves kept about 90 per cent of what they produced. Because these scholars also found that agricultural slavery was 35 per cent more efficient than family farming in the North, they argue that slaves actually may have shared in the overall benefits resulting from the gang system. Other scholars contend that slaves in fact kept less than half of what they produced and that slavery, while profitable, certainly was not efficient (Vedder, 1975; Ransom and Sutch, 1977, 1988).

Gavin Wright (1978, 2006) critiques the work of Fogel and Engerman by focusing on the exceptional nature of the crop year they used to calculate their statistics and by using alternative data to attack their estimates of total factor productivity. Wright calls attention as well to the difference between the short run and the long run. He notes that slaves accounted for a very large proportion of most masters’ portfolios of assets. Although slavery might seem an efficient means of production at a point in time, it ties masters to a certain system of labor that may not adapt quickly to changed economic circumstances.

Wright’s argument has some merit. Although the South’s growth rate compared favorably with that of the North in the antebellum period, a considerable portion of wealth was held in the hands of planters – and much of that ‘wealth’ depended upon the accounting convention of treating the human capital embodied by slaves as personal property owned by slaveholders. The consequence was a far different portfolio from that of the North, where immobile land was the largest investment. Consequently,

The economics of slavery 217

commercial and service industries lagged in the South. The region also had far less rail transportation and internal improvements than the North (Wahl, 2007).

Yet many plantations used the most advanced technologies of the day, and certain innovative commercial and insurance practices appeared first in transactions involving slaves (Wahl, 1998). In Cuba, planters were behind the move to construct railroads (Moreno Fraginals et al., 1993). Slaveowners led in using new inventions, such as the circular saw (Wahl, 1998). What is more, although the South fell behind the North and Great Britain in its level of manufacturing, it compared favorably to other advanced countries of the time. In sum, no clear consensus emerges as to whether the antebellum South created a standard of living comparable to that of the North or, if it did, whether it could have sustained it.

Profitability and efficiency of slavery elsewhere

What of the profitability and efficiency of slavery in places and times other than the ancient world and the antebellum Americas? Much less empirical economic work exists on slavery elsewhere, although Orlando Patterson (1982) and Eugene Genovese (1974) portray slavery in Islamic societies as nonproductive.

Yet to the extent that slaves perform domestic and other chores, they free masters from drudgery and therefore confer some benefits, though not necessarily market profits. Even slaves who appear merely ornamental must provide some pleasure to the masters, or else they would go free. We can still consider slavery an economic enterprise simply because it provides more benefits to their owners – pecuniary or otherwise – than costs.

Slavery in modern times

Rising British sentiment against slavery culminated in the Somerset case, which outlawed slavery in England in 1772.1 Britain and the US abolished the international slave trade in 1807–8; Britain freed slaves in its colonies (except India) in 1833, with full emancipation in 1838. Slavery in the US officially disappeared by the end of the American Civil War in 1865.

Abolition came later elsewhere, often accompanied by a rise in other forms of servitude (Watson, 1991). Eastern Europe and Russia kept slavery alive into the late nineteenth century. In 1890, all major European countries, the US, Turkey, Persia, and Zanzibar signed the General Act of Brussels in an attempt to suppress slavery. Forty years later, an international labor convention acted to outlaw forced labor in the former Ottoman and German colonies. In 1948, the UN General Assembly declared that all forms of slavery and servitude should be abolished (Bush, 1996).

218 Property law and economics

Yet slavery in Southeast Asia, the Arabian peninsula, and parts of Africa continued well into the twentieth century (Watson, 1980; Lovejoy, 1983; Klein, 1990 and 1993). Perhaps the saddest legacy of American slavery is that the system established to supply the New World with slaves also shaped society at home. Some scholars believe that slavery was endemic to Africa, others date its origins to medieval Muslim society or the later European infiltration. Regardless of beginnings, slavery within Africa burgeoned along with the Atlantic trade – in 1600 Africa had a minority of the world’s slaves, in 1800 the overwhelming majority. The Great Scramble for Africa spread slavery further. Regrettably, the tragedy continues: Angolan slaves fought bloodily for freedom in 1961, Mauritania kept slavery legal until 1980, Nigeria still had slave concubinage in the late 1980s; and numerous African regions actively practice slavery today.

Some of the harshest forms of slavery have arrived only recently. Modern weaponry, increased population density, and mass communication and transportation technology have made it that much easier to capture and move purported enemies as well as to incite one’s allies to do the same. The classic mechanism of modern slavery, patterned after the practices of Nazi Germany and the Soviet Union, is this: Officials in power arrest suspected opponents of the current political regime, or those considered racially or nationally unfit, and throw them into forced-labor camps to work under terrible conditions.

Unlike slaves in earlier societies, the unfortunates who landed in Nazi and Soviet concentration camps were not privately owned and traded in open markets. Rather, they served as property of the state, sometimes to be rented out to private interests.

Modern slaves consequently represent something far different than their historic counterparts. From pre-classical times through the nineteenth century, masters – including public entities – typically viewed their slaves as productive investments, as bookkeeping entries in their wealth portfolios, as forms of valuable capital. Slaves in these circumstances could often count on minimal food, shelter, and clothing, and time for rest and sleep. This was true even for government-owned slaves, because these slaves were typically used in money-making enterprises that just happened to be government-run, and they could potentially be sold to private owners. Not so for the ‘publicly owned’ slaves of the twentieth century. Because these people were ‘acquired’ at very low cost with public money and served primarily as political symbols, their masters had little incentive to care for them as assets.

To be sure, when Nazi Germany needed labor to fuel production of her war machinery, the country turned to the inmates of concentration camps. Likewise, the Soviets rounded up peasants to work on public projects and

The economics of slavery 219

mineral extraction. Various regions across Africa, Asia, America, and Europe have done the same. Yet these sorts of ‘slaves’ are often worth more dead than alive. Killing one’s political adversaries makes the state that much easier to run. Exterminating those labeled as unfit ‘cleanses’ society – in a truly twisted sense of the word – and binds together the ‘chosen.’ Accordingly, modern forms of mass slavery seem far different institutions than those of earlier times.

Re-examining the economics of slavery

Despite differences between modern slavery and its earlier counterparts, slavery in any time and place cannot be thought of as benign. In terms of material conditions, diet, and treatment, slaves in some societies may have fared as well as the poorest class of free citizens. Yet the root of slavery is coercion. By its very nature, slavery involves involuntary transactions. Slaves are property, whereas free laborers are persons who make choices (at times constrained, of course) about the sort of work they do and the number of hours they work.

The behavior of American ex-slaves after abolition clearly reveals that they cared strongly about the manner of their work and valued their nonwork time more highly than masters did. Even the most benevolent former masters in the US South, for instance, found it impossible to entice their former chattels back into gang work, even with large wage premiums. Nor could they persuade women back into the labor force: many female exslaves simply chose to stay at home (Fogel and Engerman, 1974).

So is slavery an economic phenomenon? Yes, but only because slave societies fail to account for the incalculable costs borne by the slaves themselves.

Note

1.Somerset v. Stewart, Loftt 1–18; 11 Herg. State Trials 339; 20 Howell’s State Trials 1, 79–82; 98 Eng Rep 499–510 (King’s Bench, 22 June 1772).

Bibliography

Aitken, Hugh (ed) (1971), Did Slavery Pay? Readings in the Economics of Black Slavery in the United States, Boston: Houghton-Mifflin.

Anstey, Roger (1975), The Atlantic Slave Trade and British Abolition, 1760–1810, London: Macmillan.

Austen, Ralph, and Woodruff Smith (1990), ‘Private Tooth Decay as Public Economic Virtue: The Slave-Sugar Triangle, Consumerism, and European Industrialization,’ Social Science History 14 (1): 95–115.

Bailey, Ronald W. (1986), ‘Africa, The Slave Trade, and the rise of industrial capitalism in Europe and the US: A historiographic review,’ American History: A Bibliographic Review, vol. 2, pp. 1–91.

Bailey, Ronald W. (1990), ‘The Slave(ry) Trade and the Development of Capitalism in

220 Property law and economics

the United States: The Textile Industry in New England,’ Social Science History 14 (3): 373–414.

Bancroft, Frederic (1931), Slave Trading in the Old South, New York: Ungar.

Barzel, Yoram (1977), ‘An Economic Analysis of Slavery,’ Journal of Law and Economics 20 (1): 87–110.

Berlin, Ira, and Herbert Gutman (1983), ‘Natives and Immigrants, Free Men and Slaves: Urban Workingmen in the Antebellum American South,’ American Historical Review 88 (5): 1175–1200.

Berlin, Ira, and Philip Morgan (eds) (1991), The Slave’s Economy: Independent Production by Slaves in the Americas, London: Frank Cass.

Berlin, Ira, and Philip Morgan (eds) (1993), Cultivation and Culture: Labor and the Shaping of Slave Life in the Americas, Charlottesville: University Press of Virginia.

Blackburn, Robin (1997), The Making of New World Slavery: From the Baroque to the Modern, London and New York: Verso.

Bloch, Marc (1975), Slavery and Serfdom in the Middle Ages, Berkeley, University of California Press.

Bush, Michael (ed) (1996), Serfdom and Slavery: Studies in Legal Bondage, New York: Addison Wesley Longman.

Campbell, Stanley W. (1968), The Slave Catchers, Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.

Coelho, Philip, and Robert A. McGuire (1997), ‘African and European Bound Labor in the British New World: The Biological Consequences of Economic Choices,’ Journal of Economic History 57 (1): 83–117.

Conrad, Alfred H., and John R. Meyer (1958), ‘The Economics of Slavery in the Antebellum South,’ Journal of Political Economy 66 (2): 95–130.

Conrad, Alfred H., and John R. Meyer (1964), The Economics of Slavery and Other Studies, Chicago: Aldine.

Darity, William, A., Jr. (1985), ‘The Numbers Game and the Profitability of the British Trade in Slaves,’ Journal of Economic History 45 (3): 693–703.

Darity, William A., Jr. (1989), ‘Comment: Profitability of the British Trade in Slaves Once Again,’ Explorations in Economic History 26 (3): 380–4.

David, Paul A., Herbert G. Gutman, Richard Sutch, Peter Temin, and Gavin Wright (1976),

Reckoning with Slavery: A Critical Study in the Quantitative History of American Negro Slavery, New York: Oxford University Press.

Dew, Charles B. (1991), Slavery in the Antebellum Southern Industries, Bethesda: University Publications of America.

Dew, Charles B. (1994), Bond of Iron: Master and Slave at Buffalo Forge, New York: Norton. Domar, Evsey (1970), ‘The Causes of Slavery or Serfdom: A Hypothesis,’ Journal of

Economic History 30 (1): 18–32.

Drescher, Seymour (1999), From Slavery to Freedom: Comparative Studies in the Rise and Fall of Atlantic Slavery, London: Macmillan Press.

Drescher, Seymour and Stanley Engerman (eds) (1998), A Historical Guide to World Slavery, New York: Oxford University Press.

Dunn, Richard S. (1972), Sugar and Slaves: The Rise of the Planter Class in the English West Indies, 1624–1713, Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.

Elkins, Stanley M. (1976), Slavery: A Problem in American Institutional and Intellectual Life, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Eltis, David (1987), Economic Growth and the Ending of the Transatlantic Slave Trade, New York: Oxford University Press.

Eltis, David (2000), The Rise of African Slavery in the Americas, New York: Cambridge University Press.

Eltis, David, and Stanley Engerman (2000), ‘The Importance of Slavery and the Slaver Trade to Industrializing Britain,’ Journal of Economic History 60 (1): 123–44.

Eltis, David, and David Richardson (1995), ‘Productivity in the Transatlantic Slave Trade,’

Explorations in Economic History 32 (4): 465–84.

The economics of slavery 221

Eltis, David, Stephen Behrendt, and David Richardson (1999), The Atlantic Slave Trade: A Database on CD-Rom, New York: Cambridge University Press.

Engerman, Stanley (1972), ‘The Slave Trade and British Capital Formation in the 18th Century: A comment on the Williams thesis,’ Business History Review 46 (4): 430–43.

Engerman, Stanley (1992), ‘Coerced and Free Labor: Property Rights and the Development of the Labor Force,’ Explorations in Economic History 29 (1): 1–29.

Engerman, Stanley, and Eugene Genovese (1975), Race and Slavery in the Western Hemisphere: Quantitative Studies, Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975.

Evans, E.W., and David Richardson (1995), ‘Hunting for Rents: The Economics of Slaving in Pre-colonial Africa,’ Economic History Review 48 (4): 665–86.

Fehrenbacher, Don (1981), Slavery, Law, and Politics, New York: Oxford University Press. Finkelman, Paul (1988), Slavery, Race, and the American Legal System, 1700–1872, 16 vol.,

New York: Garland.

Finkelman, Paul (1989a), State Slavery Statutes, Frederick, MD: University Publications of America (microfiche).

Finkelman, Paul (1989b), Articles on American Slavery, 18 vol., New York: Garland. Finley, Moses (ed.) (1961), Slavery in Classical Antiquity, New York: Barnes and Noble. Finley, Moses (ed) (1987), Classical Slavery, London: Frank Cass.

Fogel, Robert W. (1989), Without Consent or Contract, New York: Norton.

Fogel, Robert W., and Stanley L. Engerman (1974), Time on the Cross: The Economics of American Negro Slavery, Boston: Little, Brown.

Foner, Laura, and Eugene Genovese (eds) (1969), Slavery in the New World: A Reader in Comparative History, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

Foner, Philip (1941), Business and Slavery, Chapel Hill: North Carolina Press. Franklin, John H. (1988), From Slavery to Freedom, New York: Knopf.

Friedman, Gerald, and Richard Manning (1992), ‘The Rent and Hire of Slaves,’ in Robert Fogel, Ralph Galantine, and Richard Manning (eds), Without Consent or Contract: Evidence and Methods, New York: Norton, pp. 77–78.

Galenson, David (1981), White Servitude in Colonial America: An Economic Analysis, New York: Cambridge University Press.

Galenson, David (1982), ‘The Atlantic Slave Trade and the Barbados Market, 1673–1723,’

Journal of Economic History 42 (3): 491–511.

Galenson, David (1984), ‘Rise and Fall of Indentured Servitude in the Americas: An Economic Analysis,’ Journal of Economic History 44 (1): 1–26.

Galenson, David W. (1986), Traders, Planters, and Slaves: Market Behavior in Early English America, New York: Cambridge University Press.

Genovese, Eugene D. (1974), Roll, Jordan, Roll, New York: Pantheon.

Genovese, Eugene D. (1989), The Political Economy of Slavery: Studies in the Economy and Society of the Slave South, Middletown, CT: Wesleyan.

Goldin, Claudia D. (1976), Urban Slavery in the American South, 1820–1860: A Quantitative History, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Goodell, William (1853), The American Slave Code, New York: Antislavery Society. Grindle, David J. (1990), ‘Manumission: The Weak Link in Georgia’s Law of Slavery,’

Mercer Law Review 41 (2): 701–22.

Grubb, Farley (1985), ‘Immigrant Servant Labor: Their Occupational and Geographic Distribution in the Late Eighteenth Century Mid-Atlantic Economy,’ Social Science History 9 (3): 249–75.

Grubb, Farley (1994), ‘The End of European Immigrant Servitude in the US: An Economic Analysis of Market Collapse, 1772–1835,’ Journal of Economic History 54 (4): 794–824.

Helper, Hinton Rowan (1857), The Impending Crisis of the South, New York: Burdick Brothers.

Higman, Barry (1976), Slave Population and Economy in Jamaica, 1807–34, New York: Cambridge University Press.

Hindus, Michael S. (1980), Prison and Plantation, Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.

222 Property law and economics

Hurd, John (1858), Law of Freedom and Bondage in the United States, Boston: Little, Brown.

Inikori, Joseph (1981), ‘Market Structure and the Profits of the British African Trade in the Late 18th Century,’ Journal of Economic History 41 (4): 745–76.

Jones, A.H.M. (1956), ‘Slavery in the Ancient World,’ Economic History Review 9 (2): 185–99.

Klein, Martin (1990), ‘The Impact of the Atlantic Slave Trade on the Societies of the Western Sudan,’ Social Science History 14 (2): 231–54.

Klein, Martin (1993), Breaking the Chains: Slavery, Bondage, and Emancipation in Modern Africa and Asia, Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.

Kolchin, Peter (1987), Unfree Labor: American Slavery and Russian Serfdom, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Kotlikoff, Laurence (1979), ‘The Structure of Slave Prices in New Orleans, 1804–1862,’

Economic Inquiry 17 (4): 496–518.

Licht, Walter (1983), Working for the Railroad: The Organization of Work in the Nineteenth Century, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Lovejoy, Paul (1983), Transformations in Slavery: A History of Slavery in Africa, New York: Cambridge University Press.

Mancall, Peter, Joshua Rosenbloom, and Thomas Weiss (2001), ‘Slave Prices and the South Carolina Economy, 1722–1809,’ Journal of Economic History 61 (3): 616–39.

Manning, Patrick (1990), ‘The Slave Trade: Formal Demography of a Global System,’ Social Science History 14 (2): 255–79.

Manning, Patrick (2006), Slavery and African Life: Occidental, Oriental, and African Slave Trades, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Margo, Robert, and Richard Steckel (1982), ‘The Heights of American Slaves: New Evidence on Slave Nutrition and Health.’ Social Science History 6 (4): 516–38.

Meltzer, Milton (ed) (1993), Slavery: A World History, New York: Da Capo Press. Menard, Russell R. (1977), ‘From Servants to Slaves: The Transformation of the

Chesapeake Labor System,’ Southern Studies 16: 355–90.

Menard, Russell R. (2006), Sweet Negotiations, Charlottesville: University of Virginia Press.

Metzer, Jacob (1975), ‘Rational Management, Modern Business Practices and Economies of Scale in the Ante-Bellum Southern Plantations,’ Explorations in Economic History 12 (2): 123–50.

Mintz, Sidney (1974), Caribbean Transformations, New York: Columbia University Press. Moreno Fraginals, Manuel, Herbert Klein, and Stanley Engerman (1993), ‘The Level and Structure of Slave Prices on Cuban Plantations in the Mid Nineteenth Century: Some

Comparative Perspectives,’ American Historical Review 88 (5): 1201–18.

Morris, Thomas D. (1996), Southern Slavery and the Law: 1619–1860, Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.

Newland, Carlos, and Maria Jesus San Segundo (1996), ‘Human Capital and Other Determinants of the Price Life Cycle of a Slave,’ Journal of Economic History 56 (3): 694–701.

Oakes, James (1982), The Ruling Race: A History of American Slaveholders, New York: Knopf.

Olmstead, Frederick Law (1861, rep. 1953), The Cotton Kingdom: A Traveler’s Observation on Cotton and Slavery in the American Slave States, ed. A.M. Schlesinger, New York: Knopf.

Parish, Peter (1989), Slavery: History and Historians, New York: Westview Press. Patterson, Orlando (1982), Slavery and Social Death: A Comparative Study, Cambridge, MA:

Harvard University Press.

Phillips, Ulrich B. (1918) American Negro Slavery: A Survey of the Supply, Employment and Control of Negro Labor as Determined by the Plantation Regime, New York: Appleton.

Phillips, Ulrich B. (1927), Life and Labor in the Old South, Boston: Little, Brown.

Phillips, William, Jr. (1985), Slavery from Roman Times to the Early Transatlantic Trade, Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.

The economics of slavery 223

Pritchett, Jonathan (1997), ‘The Interregional Slave Trade and the Selection of Slaves for the New Orleans Market,’ Journal of Interdisciplinary History 28 (1): 57–85.

Ramsdell, Charles W. (1929), ‘The Natural Limits of Slavery Expansion,’ Mississippi Valley Historical Review 16 (2): 151–71.

Ransom, Roger L. (1989), Conflict and Compromise, New York: Cambridge University Press.

Ransom, Roger L., and Richard Sutch (1977), One Kind of Freedom: The Economic Consequences of Emancipation, New York: Cambridge University Press.

Ransom, Roger L., and Richard Sutch (1988), ‘Capitalists Without Capital: The Burden of Slavery and the Impact of Emancipation,’ Agricultural History 62 (3): 133–60.

Richardson, David (1987), ‘The Costs of Survival: The Transport of Slaves in the Middle Passage and the Profitability of the 18th Century British Slave Trade,’ Explorations in Economic History 24 (2): 178–96.

Richardson, David (1989), ‘Accounting for Profits in the British Trade in Slaves: A Reply to Darity,’ Explorations in Economic History 26 (4): 492–9.

Roark, James L. (1977), Masters Without Slaves, New York: Norton.

Scarborough, William K. (1966), The Overseer: Plantation Management in the Old South, Baton Rouge, Louisiana State University Press.

Schafer, Judith K. (1994), Slavery, The Civil Law, and the Supreme Court of Louisiana, Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press.

Schmitz, Mark, and Donald Schaefer (1981), ‘Paradox Lost: Westward Expansion and Slave Prices Before the Civil War,’ Journal of Economic History 41 (2): 402–7.

Sheridan, Richard B. (1947), Sugar and Slavery: An Economic History of the British West Indies, 1607–1776, Barbados: Caribbean University Press.

Solow, Barbara, and Stanley Engerman (1987), Capitalism and Caribbean Slavery: The Legacy of Eric Williams, New York: Cambridge University Press.

Stampp, Kenneth M. (1956), The Peculiar Institution: Slavery in the Antebellum South, New York: Knopf.

Starobin, Robert (1970), Industrial Slavery in the Old South, New York: Oxford University Press.

Steckel, Richard (1986a), ‘Birth Weights and Infant Mortality Among American Slaves,’

Explorations in Economic History 23 (2): 173–98.

Steckel, Richard (1986b), ‘A Peculiar Population: The Nutrition, Health, and Mortality of American Slaves from Childhood to Maturity,’ Journal of Economic History 46 (3): 721–41.

Steinfeld, Robert J. (1991), The Invention of Free Labor: The Employment Relation in English and American Law and Culture, 1350–1870, Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.

Stroud, George (1856), A Sketch of the Laws Relating to Slavery in the Several States of the USA, New York: Negro University Press.

Tadman, Michael (1990), Speculators and Slaves, Madison: University of Wisconsin Press. Tushnet, Mark V. (1981), The American Law of Slavery, 1810–60: Considerations of

Humanity and Interest, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Vedder, Richard K. (1975), ‘The Slave Exploitation (Expropriation) Rate,’ Explorations in Economic History 12 (4): 453–7.

Wahl, Jenny B. (1998), The Bondsman’s Burden: An Economic Analysis of the Common Law of Southern Slavery, New York: Cambridge University Press.

Wahl, Jenny B. (2007), ‘Stay East, Young Man? Market Repercussions of the Dred Scott decision,’ Chicago-Kent Law Review 82 (1): 361–91.

Walvin, James (1992), Black Ivory: A History of British Slavery, Washington, DC: Howard University Press.

Watson, Alan (1987), Roman Slave Law, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press.

Watson, Alan (1989), Slave Law in the Americas, Athens, GA: University of Georgia Press. Watson, Alan (1991), Roman Law and Comparative Law, Athens, GA: University of Georgia

Press.

224 Property law and economics

Watson, James (ed) (1980), Asian and African Systems of Slavery, Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.

Westermann, William (1943), ‘Slavery and the Elements of Freedom in Ancient Greece,’

Quarterly Bulletin of the Polish Institute of Arts and Sciences in America 1 (January): 1–16.

Wheeler, Jacob (1837), A Practical Treatise on the Law of Slavery, New York: Allan Pollack, Jr.

Wiecek, William M. (1977), ‘The Statutory Law of Slavery and Race in the Thirteen Mainland Colonies of British America,’ William and Mary Quarterly 34 (2): 258–80.

Williams, Eric (1944), Capitalism and Slavery, Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.

Wright, Gavin (1978), The Political Economy of the Cotton South: Households, Markets, and Wealth in the Nineteenth Century, New York: Norton.

Wright, Gavin (2006), Slavery and American Economic Development, Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press.

Yasuba, Yasukichi (1961), ‘The Profitability and Viability of Slavery in the US,’ Economic Studies Quarterly 12 (September): 60–7.

Yeager, Timothy J. (1995), ‘Encomienda or Slavery? The Spanish Crown’s Choice of Labor Organization in Sixteenth Century Spanish America,’ Journal of Economic History 55 (4): 842–59.